Chapter 7: Crisis Economics – Shocks, Speculation & Emergency Behavior
Objective:
To understand how crises—be they pandemics, wars, inflation shocks, or
policy upheavals—alter market behavior through speculation, hoarding,
panic-buying, and black marketing. This chapter explores these disruptions
using analytical models, real-world case studies, and graphical insights.
1.
Introduction: When Logic Breaks and Emotion Buys
Markets function on signals: price indicates scarcity, cost reflects effort,
and consumers optimize utility. But during crises, this neat logic collapses.
Crises incite emergency behavior, where fear outweighs
rational decision-making. Buyers hoard, speculators hype, and sellers shift to
informal channels where prices are unregulated.
What emerges is a fragile ecosystem of:
·
Speculative Demand – Driven by
fear or expectations
·
Hoarding – Suppliers reduce
supply intentionally or due to fear of shortage
·
Black Markets – Arise due to
legal price controls or bans
·
Price Volatility – As
expectations and reality move apart
These distortions are not outliers—they are part of the crisis
economics framework, a necessity to understand how the market fails
and how it can be rescued.
2.
Crisis Shocks: Categories and Implications
Economic crises can arise from internal or external shocks. Each affects
market behavior differently:
Shock Type |
Examples |
Market Impact |
Supply Shocks |
War, natural disasters, factory closures |
Supply ↓, Prices ↑ |
Demand Shocks |
Pandemic panic, oil demand crash |
Demand ↑ or ↓, Supply lagging |
Currency Shocks |
Rupee devaluation, capital outflows |
Import prices ↑, Cost-push inflation |
Policy Shocks |
Bans, sudden taxation, lockdowns |
Legal markets paralyzed, informal sectors grow |
: Crises create ripple effects where rational economic agents behave
unpredictably, pushing systems into chaos if not corrected with intelligent
policy.
3. Rewriting the
Equations of Demand and Supply Under Stress
Modified Demand Equation in a Crisis:
Qd = α – βP + γE + δF + θM
Where:
·
P = Price
·
E = Expectation of future price rise
·
F = Fear/Panic Index (ranging 0–1)
·
M = Media/Information pressure
·
γ, δ, θ are parameters measuring how
external shocks distort logical demand
During crises, γE + δF + θM dominate the equation—people
buy more because they’re scared, not because of price or need.
Modified Supply Equation in a Crisis:
Qs = a + bP – cH + dT – φR
Where:
·
H = Hoarding impact (intended or
unintended supply withdrawal)
·
T = Delay due to logistical constraints
·
R = Regulatory bottlenecks
·
φ = Negative elasticity due to
interference
Interpretation: Supply doesn’t just respond to price but is
blocked or slowed by fear, hoarding, or poor governance. This results in the
supply curve shifting leftward during crisis.
4. Graphical Insight:
Panic Buying and Hoarding Converge
Below is a visual representation of how markets behave during crises.
Key Observations:
·
Demand shifts right (from D1 to D2) due to
panic, expectation, and hype.
·
Supply shifts left (from S1 to S2) due to
hoarding and delays.
·
Price increases from P1 (₹66.67)
to P2 (₹76.67).
·
Quantity available falls from Q1 (2333
units) to Q2 (2233 units).
The gap between official and black market price
widens—fertile ground for profiteers and economic inequality.
5.
Case Studies of Crisis-Induced Market Behavior
Case 1: COVID-19 and Sanitizer Panic (2020)
In March–April 2020, a 100ml sanitizer bottle that cost ₹50 before the
pandemic was selling at ₹300–₹500 in several regions of India.
·
Hoarding by distributors reduced available
supply.
·
Fearful consumers overbought (panic multiplier).
·
Government interventions came late, allowing
black markets to flourish.
The modified equations in action:
Qd = 3000 – 10P + 400 (panic)
Qs = 1000 + 20P – 300 (hoarding)
New Equilibrium:
3000 – 10P = 700 + 20P → P = ₹76.67, Q = 2233 units
Compared to the normal: P = ₹66.67, Q = 2333 units.
This is not just inflation—it’s distortion.
Case 2: Russia-Ukraine War and Wheat Prices (2022)
Ukraine and Russia accounted for over 30% of global wheat exports. The war
led to:
·
Export bans
·
Transportation disruptions
·
Surge in futures buying by speculators
·
Domestic hoarding by governments and households
Prices increased by over 40% in global markets. Even non-importing countries
saw spikes due to expectation-based demand and supply
chain mimicry.
Case 3: Bitcoin and Cryptocurrency Boom-Bust Cycle (2020–22)
Unlike essential goods, cryptocurrencies exhibited pure speculative
demand.
·
Demand driven not by use, but by media,
influencer hype, and fear of missing out (FOMO).
·
Price surged from $8000 to $64000 in 18 months.
·
Crashed below $20000 in early 2022 as fear
reversed.
This reflects the γE + θM term dominating the demand
equation.
6.
Numerical Caselet: Crisis Price Prediction
Scenario:
During a sudden disease outbreak, consumers start panic-buying medical gloves.
Government data shows:
·
Pre-crisis: Qd = 4000 – 15P, Qs = 1500 + 25P
·
In-crisis: Panic index (F) = 0.75, Hoarding
index (H) = 40 units
Modified:
·
Qd = 4000 – 15P + 500F = 4000 – 15P + 375 = 4375
– 15P
·
Qs = 1500 + 25P – 40×10 = 1100 + 25P
Find Equilibrium:
4375 – 15P = 1100 + 25P
⇒
3275 = 40P
⇒
P = ₹81.88
⇒
Q = 1100 + 25×81.88 = 1100 + 2047 = 3147 units
Result:
·
Price increase of 30%
·
Quantity drop of 400–500 units
·
Panic increased demand even as hoarding reduced
supply
7.
Emergency Behavior: Irrationality is Rational in Fear
Crises disrupt assumptions of rationality.
Observed Behaviors:
·
Stockpiling – Beyond logical
use
·
Speculation – Buy now, sell at
peak
·
Informal Markets – Legal
channels can’t serve excess demand
These are rational strategies under uncertainty, but they create
externalities that hurt the broader economy—especially the poor and
marginalized.
8.
Policy Intervention: Taming the Crisis Monster
Discussion Prompt:
Design a 4-point Market Stabilization Policy Toolkit for
governments.
Toolkit:
1. Real-Time
Inventory Dashboards
o
Use AI and logistics to monitor stock movement
across regions.
2. Temporary
Price Caps + Incentive Bonuses
o
Cap prices but reward efficient sellers with tax
rebates or fuel subsidies.
3. Information
Campaigns
o
Reduce media-driven panic via expert-led
communication.
4. Enforcement
Against Hoarding & Black Marketing
o
Use legal power to confiscate hoarded goods and
redistribute them publicly.
9. Long-Term Institutional Measures
Crisis economics teaches us the need for proactive rather than reactive
frameworks:
·
National Crisis Resilience Units
·
Digital Supply Chain Monitoring
·
Commodity Futures Regulation During
Emergencies
·
Integration of Psychological Economics
in Policy Design
Markets aren’t perfect. But systems can be.
10. Conclusion: The Invisible Hand Doesn’t Work When It's
Tied
In times of peace and certainty, markets self-regulate well. But crises
expose their soft underbelly. Demand overshoots, supply collapses, and
equilibrium is broken not just economically but socially.
Speculation and hoarding aren't just strategies—they are symptoms of
broken trust in institutions and systems.
Crisis economics is not about controlling every move—but about creating flexible
safety nets, accurate real-time data, and a public psychology of stability.
Teaching
Notes & Reflection Questions
1. Why
do people overbuy during a crisis? Does it make economic sense individually?
2. Plot
a graph showing black-market pricing. How does it hurt consumer surplus?
3. If
expectations can drive demand more than price, how can you regulate
"expectation"?
4. Is
hoarding always unethical? What if it’s for personal safety or future scarcity?
5. Design
a simulation model to detect panic-driven buying in essential goods.
Case
Study : The Onion Crisis in India – A Case of Speculation, Hoarding, and Policy
Gaps
Background:
Onions are an essential staple in Indian
kitchens, and their price volatility is a politically sensitive issue. In
multiple years—2006, 2010, 2013, 2019, and 2023—India witnessed massive spikes
in onion prices, often due to a mix of unseasonal
rainfall, poor storage infrastructure,
hoarding by traders, and policy failures.
Event
Timeline (2019 Example):
·
June–July:
Unseasonal rain in Maharashtra damaged standing crops.
·
August:
Market arrivals declined sharply.
·
September:
Prices began to climb rapidly, touching ₹100/kg in retail markets.
·
October:
Traders and middlemen hoarded stocks in cold storages.
·
November:
Government imposed export bans and capped stock limits.
·
December:
Prices surged to ₹150/kg in major cities like Delhi and Mumbai.
Modified
Demand and Supply Dynamics:
Let’s analyze this using our crisis model.
Normal
Conditions:
·
Demand: Qd = 5000 – 12P
·
Supply: Qs = 2000 + 25P
Crisis
Conditions:
·
Crop loss reduced supply by 600 units (weather
shock)
·
Hoarding effect = 300 units
·
Panic buying added 400 units to demand
New
Equations:
·
Qd = 5000
– 12P + 400 = 5400 – 12P
·
Qs = 2000
+ 25P – 600 – 300 = 1100 + 25P
Equilibrium:
5400 – 12P = 1100 + 25P
⇒
4300 = 37P
⇒
P = ₹116.22/kg, Q ≈ 3105 kg
Black
Market Insight:
In cities where rationing was introduced, a
parallel market emerged:
·
Official supply (rationed): 2 kg/person at
₹60/kg
·
Black market price: ₹140–₹160/kg
·
Traders sold stored onions discreetly to
restaurants, hotels, and local vendors
Public
Response:
·
Citizens protested outside mandis.
·
Memes and outrage flooded social media.
·
Politicians blamed each other; policy became
reactive instead of preventive.
·
Imports from Egypt, Afghanistan, and Turkey were
arranged late.
Teaching
Notes:
Lessons
Learned:
1.
Lack of
preemptive action on weather data worsened the situation.
2.
Storage without
monitoring enabled hoarding.
3.
Import decisions
should have been made earlier.
4.
Price caps
without real-time stock control pushed sales underground.
Reflection
Questions:
·
What early-warning systems could prevent a
repeat of the onion crisis?
·
Should essential commodities be placed under
price surveillance like fuel?
·
How can supply chain transparency be improved at
the mandi level?
·
Should India regulate speculative storage of
food items?
Policy
Suggestions (Post-Crisis Recommendations):
·
Smart
mandi surveillance using RFID/barcodes for stock entry and exit
·
Buffer
stock with public-private storage partnerships
·
Real-time
price and volume dashboards at national and state levels
·
Seasonal
crop insurance for volatile vegetables
This case study shows how Crisis Economics is not just about
macro-level disruptions like pandemics or wars, but also local, seasonal events
that affect millions of consumers. The onion crisis underscores the power of
speculation, the fragility of supply chains, and the importance of proactive
policy
Comments
Post a Comment